class: center, middle, inverse, title-slide .title[ # ECON 366: Energy Economics ] .subtitle[ ## Topic 5.1: Climate Change Policies ] .author[ ### Andrew Leach, Professor of Economics and Law ] .date[ ### December 3, 2023
aleach@ualberta.ca
leachandrew
@andrew_leach
] --- <!--[test link](weekly_jan_18.html#featured-chart)--> <style type="text/css"> hr.space-1 { background: transparent; color: transparent; margin: 0; height: 1rem; } hr.space { background: transparent; color: transparent; margin: 0; height: 1em; } blockquote { border-left: .5px solid #275d38; margin: 15px 80px -25px 20px; padding-top: -0.5px; padding-bottom: -0.5px; line-height: 1.35em; } .cite_quote { margin: -80px 80px 25px 100px; padding-top: -0.5px; padding-bottom: -0.5px; line-height: 1em; font-size: 20px; } .cite { margin: -20px 80px -25px 80px; padding-top: -0.5px; padding-bottom: -0.5px; line-height: 1.25em; font-size: 20px; } .space blockquote { margin: -25px 50px -25px 50px; padding-top: -0.5px; padding-bottom: -0.5px; } .space blockquote p { line-height: 1em; } .site_link { font-size: 16px; } .blockquote { margin: 2em 0px -1em 0px; } .hr.space-1 { background: transparent; color: transparent; margin: 0; height: 1rem; } </style> # Climate Policy Tools The goal of this deck is to introduce you to the main climate policy tools: - regulation - carbon taxes - cap-and-trade regimes - hybrid policies You should also be able to demonstrate that you: - Understand the attributes of the different policies - Understand each policy's strengths and weaknesses - Know the examples I've given you of each policy type --- # The Basic Environmental Economics Problem <img src="climate_policy_files/figure-html/ext_dwl-1.png" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> --- # The Reduced Form Environmental Economics Toolkit <img src="climate_policy_files/figure-html/mac_md-1.png" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> --- # Emissions Permits? How much will they be worth? <img src="climate_policy_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-3-1.png" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> --- # Emissions Taxes <img src="climate_policy_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-4-1.png" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> --- # Types of Climate Policies for Discussion Market-based tools: - carbon taxes - a fee per unit emissions or a fee per unit deemed emissions in fuels - cap-and-trade systems - fixed number of emissions *rights* and a system for trading those rights Regulatory tools: - regulatory regimes - technology standards, emissions limits or caps, fuel or electricity content standards - regulatory regimes may also have tradeable compliance credits (renewable fuel or electricity standards, for example) --- # Types of Climate Policies for Discussion Spending tools: - subsidies - feed-in tariffs, production tax credits, investment tax credits, etc. Hybrids policies (flexible regulations) are almost always what gets implemented Combinations of most of the above now exist in many jurisdictions --- # Command-and-control measures This is a broad category of measures that basically involve the government regulating one of: - Technology (e.g. A ban on coal power) - Performance (e.g. emissions intensity or fuel economy standards) - Emissions output (licensing rules on facilities) - Siting or permitting regulations (IAA, SARA, etc.) --- # Command-and-control measures Federal and provincial programs currently implement standards of all different types > Small engines (Off-Road Small Spark-Ignition Engine Emission Regulations, SOR/2003-355 under CEPA, 1999) > Light duty vehicles (SOR/2014-207 under CEPA, 1999) > Alberta regulates upstream venting and flaring (AER Directive 60) > Federal Reduction of Carbon Dioxide Emissions from Coal-fired Generation of Electricity Regulations (SOR/2012-167 CEPA, 1999) --- # Command-and-control measures Economic critiques - Requires a lot of information on the part of government - Limited incentive to innovate - May require very expensive emissions reductions from some facilities while ignoring cheap opportunities elsewhere --- # Market-based approaches Easiest (IMO) to start with two questions: - Who has the right to emit by default or how is such a right obtained? - Are rights scarce in the economic sense – do they bind total emissions? Market-based approaches to emissions control essentially: - create and distribute regulatory rights (or licenses) to emit or, equivalently, exemptions from tax on emissions - Enforce a requirement that emissions be less than held licenses/rights/exemptuions, or to pay a tax on emissions net of rights/licenses/exemptions --- # Market-based approaches Cap-and-trade programs are the prototypical market-based approach for pollution First implemented widely in the context of acid rain in the 1990s Now implemented in the European Union (EU-ETS) and in a joint Quebec-California market (WCI) among others for carbon emissions Implementation in each market varies in terms of: - Distribution rules, including share of rights that are auctioned vs allocated freely - Safety valves, including reserves of rights that are made available if prices climb too high - Trading rules – in some markets there are clawbacks when rights are exchanged --- # Market-based approaches Example : [Quebec’s cap-and-trade system](https://canlii.ca/t/554w4) - Who is an emitter? (s. 2) - What must an emitter do, including registration, reporting, etc. (Title II, Ch. 2) - What GHG emissions are included and how entities must quantify their emissions and use allowances or offset credits to cover these emissions (Title II, Ch. 3) - Rules for transactions of emissions allowances (Title II, Ch. 4) including limits on banking of allowances - Emissions allowances (ss. 36-7), reserve allowances (s 38), free allocation (s. 39), auctions (ss 45-64) including minimum prices (s 49), and other ways to receive allowances (ss 65-70) Remainder of the Regulation includes penalties for violation and appendices establishing industry-level conditions --- # Market-based approaches Example : [Quebec’s cap-and-trade system](https://canlii.ca/t/554w4) The system has been expanded to recognized allowances from the California and, at one point, Ontario systems for compliance in Quebec From an individual firm’s point of view, the markets are unified and you can purchase or sell allowances to entities in any market. In practical terms, this ensures a common price between California and Quebec --- # Market-based approaches Pure cap-and-trade approaches provide quantity certainty and let the market determine the price of allowances/offsets/licenses/rights to emit The introduction of price mitigation (reserve allowances, etc.) cuts against that price certainty, allowing emissions to rise if prices get too high Average cost of the policy to firms depends on the emissions allowances allocated free of charge, the auction prices, and perhaps the volatility of prices through the year Marginal cost – the value of an incremental emission or emissions reduction – is determined by the market price for allowances --- # Market-based approaches Economists favour market-based approaches in general because of: - Limited information requirements compared to facility-specific standards - Market mechanism ensures cost-effectiveness – facilities with cheapest emissions reductions will reduce first, and more expensive reductions will not be undertaken - Incentives to innovate are strong, since lowering emissions allows for the sale of allowances and/or avoided purchases Environmentalists have tended to favour cap-and-trade approaches because of emissions certainty, although that was challenged by relatively weak targets in the EU for many years --- # Carbon taxes A carbon tax sees the government act, effectively, as the default seller of emissions allowances and total emissions are not capped - Prototypical carbon tax implemented in BC in 2007 - A reasonable proxy for a carbon tax in some ways is implemented in Canada under the Greenhouse Gas Pollution Pricing Act (GGPPA), but that’s better described as a hybrid policy --- # Key attributes of a carbon tax regime - Coverage (which emissions or which facilities/sectors/etc) - Stringency (how much is the tax) - Exemptions and credits (are there ways to avoid the tax) Average cost of the policy to firms will generally be equal to the price ($/tonne) applied through the tax Marginal cost – the value of an incremental emission or emissions reduction – is the same as the average cost: the value of the tax --- # Carbon taxes Example: BC's [Carbon Tax Act, SBC 2008, c 40](https://www.canlii.org/en/bc/laws/stat/sbc-2008-c-40/latest/sbc-2008-c-40.html) What’s covered by the tax? fuel at point of purchase (s. 8) or imported fuel (ss. 9-10) or fuel used in BC that was not otherwise taxed (s. 11) Exemptions (s 14) and credits (ss 14.1 – 14.2) Collection mechanics and penalties Carbon tax rates for different fuels (Schedule 1) --- # Carbon taxes Economists favour carbon taxes for the same reasons as cap-and-trade: - Limited information requirements compared to facility-specific standards - Market mechanism ensures cost-effectiveness – only emissions reductions which cost less than the tax will be undertaken, since otherwise it makes more sense to pay the tax - Incentives to innovate are strong, since lowering emissions allows for avoided carbon tax payments Environmentalists have tended to favour cap-and-trade approaches because of emissions certainty - Skepticism of carbon taxes has historically also focused on regressive elements of the tax on fuels --- # Hybrid policies Most emissions pricing policies contain some elements from each policy type > Flexible regulations: regulations with some ability to trade credits for over-compliance or to substitute with financial compliance (i.e. paying a fee) > Output-based pricing systems: elements of cap-and-trade (allowance issuance, trading rules, offsets) combined with carbon taxes (gov’t sets a fixed price for sale of reserve allowances) The [GGPPA](https://canlii.ca/t/944q), for example, has a consumer carbon tax combined with an output-based pricing system for larger emitters Alberta’s Alberta's [Technology, Innovation and Emissions Reduction Regulation](https://canlii.ca/t/54qgg) is an output-based pricing system with government as default seller of carbon credits Renewable fuel and vehicle emissions regulations allow flexible compliance (trading) Clean Fuel Standard allows for flexible compliance and a credit market --- #Hybrid policies Example: Alberta's [TIER Regulation](https://canlii.ca/t/54qgg) Facilities emitting more than 100kt/yr are covered (s.3), with an opt-in (s.4) or aggregation (s.5) for facilities emitting more than 10kt/yr if there is a covered, competitor facility Each product has a benchmark, which you can think of as a rate at which allowances are issued (0.2974 tonnes of allowances per barrel of bitumen, for example) (s.6) Facilities may have facility-specific benchmarks (s. 7) Facilities where compliance costs exceed competitiveness thresholds may qualify for a higher benchmark (s.8) --- #Hybrid policies Example: Alberta's [TIER Regulation](https://canlii.ca/t/54qgg) Facilities must report emissions and output, as well as on-site heat and power generation if applicable Allowable emissions (s. 9) are equal to the sum of: - Allocation rate times output for each product net of: - Allocation rate for net electricity exports - Credits for imported hydrogen or heat --- #Hybrid policies Example: Alberta's [TIER Regulation](https://canlii.ca/t/54qgg) Any gap between allowable and actual emissions must be trued-up (s. 13(2)) by: - Retirement of emissions offsets - Retirement of emissions performance credits banked from a previous year or bought from another facility - Payments to the government to buy credits from the Fund at a fixed price per tonne A facility which has more allowable than actual emissions may be issued emissions performance credits (s. 20) which can be banked or traded --- # Hybrid policies Key differences between a program like TIER and a pure carbon tax charged on every tonne of emissions will be the average cost of compliance - Benchmarks effectively act like refundable tax credits, giving facilities some free emissions - Hybrid programs can still provide a strong incentive to reduce emissions at operating facilities, while not encouraging reductions in output - The output-based allocation or benchmark is effectively an output subsidy - Hybrid programs have very different implications for investment or divestment/shut-in decisions, since they affect the average profitability less than a pure carbon tax - Output-based allocations of credits can also exist in cap-and-trade systems, just as output-based tax credits might be issued under a carbon tax. > No bright line between carbon pricing, carbon taxes, cap-and-trade, and hybrid policies